This review has been accessed times since April 8, 2001

Birnbaum, Robert. (2000). Management fads in higher education: Where they come from, what they do, why they fail. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.

xxii + 287.
$32.95       ISBN 0-7879-4456-4.

Reviewed by Bob Barnetson
Alberta Colleges & Institutes Faculties Association

April 8, 2001

Bordering at times on the epidemiological, Robert Birnbaum's Management fads in higher education traces the history of seven management fads in American higher education to develop a compelling model of the fad process and the transmission of fads to higher education. Subsequently, he posits characteristics and factors that make institutions vulnerable to fads and suggests why managers implement them. Finally, Birnbaum examines the legacy of fads in higher education. Underlying this cathartic book is Birnbaum's belief that the techniques and technologies we use are not neutral but rather embody particular ideological beliefs.

Management fads are the widespread, zealous and blessedly short-lived application of techniques or practices in colleges, universities and technical institutes, often imported from government or the private sector long after the bloom is off. Ever fashionable and frequently messianic, fads offer convincing narratives, illuminate better ways of doing things, reduce ambiguity (as well as diversity), shift power between actors, and make consultants big, big piles of money.

Birnbaum presents seven case studies of recent management fads. These include Planning Programming Budgeting System (1960-1975), Management by Objectives (1965-1980), Zero- Based Budgeting (1970-1985), Strategic Planning (1972-1994), Benchmarking (1979-present), Total Quality Management (1985-1996), and Business Process Reengineering (1990-1996). All of these fads differ from the scientific management that was ascendant between 1900 and the end of the second world war. The post-war massification of higher education saw the adoption of numerous management techniques and technologies to increase cost-effectiveness. Rationality became the hallmark of academic management as new decision-making systems attempted to reduce ambiguity and increase internal consistency, even at the expense of desirable outcomes.

Based on the seven case studies presented in Chapters Two, Three and Four, Birnbaum outlines the five-stage progression of management fads. The first stage is characterized by the identification of a crisis that (coincidentally) invalidates existing operating assumptions. Early adopters of the fad enthusiastically report on its success, providing proponents with evidence that the fad can resolve the crisis. This triggers interest among other organizations. Criticism of the technique is deflected via the presentation of simplified versions of the fad, distancing it from previous fads, and intense rhetoric about what is at stake should the fad not be implemented.

As momentum builds, the fad moves to stage two. Early reports of success become elaborated and widespread and organizational peer pressure builds as adopters receive accolades. Little attention is given to the potential costs of the technique and resisters are denigrated as self- interested or intransigent. The time between widespread dissemination of the fad and widespread knowledge of user reactions and independent analysis is the third stage. Although the fad continues to receive positive press, counter-narratives begin to emerge. Interestingly, analysis in the private sector tends to be quantitative (perhaps reflecting profit-driven criteria) while analysis in academe tends to be interpretative. In the fourth stage, momentum swings to these counter-narratives and the claims about the fad's effectiveness begin to be undermined. The growing bad press effectively inoculates institutions against adoption although current users may discount these reports to protect their financial and psychological investment in the fad.

Widespread rationalization of the fad's failure—particularly among promoters eager to protect both their status and their epistemological assumptions—is its death knell. Birnbaum details the preferred rationalizations, such as poor leadership, improper implementation, and lack of resources. Less popular is the notion that a technique was based upon invalid premises. For example, underlying most fads is the belief that organizations work like machines. That is to say, organizations are rational, possessing clear goals and operating via an understandable (and therefore manipulable) causality. Although several alternative metaphors have emerged (cf. Cohen, March and Olsen, 1972; Birnbaum, 1988; Morgan, 1997; Cutright, 2001), the mechanical metaphor for organizations endures, perhaps because it suggests organizations can be controlled.

Birnbaum argues that several factors pressure institutions to adopt management fads. Predominant, to my mind, is the culture of crisis wherein political and ideological agendas are pursued through criticism of goals, processes, and outcomes. Where these claims stick, institutions or systems are vulnerable to the introduction of value-laden management fads. For example, in my jurisdiction (Alberta, Canada) performance funding was ostensibly introduced to address ill-defined problems with institutional accountability and performance. Although there is little evidence that accountability or performance has improved (or needed to), "our" performance indicators now act as a conceptual technology—shaping what issues we think about and how we think about them (Barnetson and Cutright, 2000). For example, measuring enrollment growth defines accessibility as the availability of seats and thus ignores the impact of rising tuition on the ability of students to afford those seats.

One institutional response to fads and their proponents is the virtual adoption of a fad. Institutions seeking approval from governments, peers, the private sector, or the public may publicly espouse the methods and jargon of a new fad. In practice, institutions (or sub-units) may not adopt the technique or process of the fads or may implement them in a way so as to limit their effect until interest passes. Given that management fads are introduced in higher education after they have come and gone in government or the private sector, waiting out the fad may be a cost-effective and culturally appropriate response. Virtual adoption also makes it easy for institutions to abandon a fad.

Successful fads—those achieving widespread notoriety and adoption—have a common set of traits. A fad that can be transmitted to other organizations via repetition will likely be successful. For example, Birnbaum asserts that individuals whose organizational perspective is structural (rather than cultural or interpretative) are more likely to be captured by a fad. They may, in turn, become key vectors for the spread of the idea. The success of a fad is also enhanced if the fad sounds reasonable (in light of our internalized beliefs about how organizations work) and if its definition is malleable enough so that its adoption will create little cognitive dissonance. When reasonableness and vague definition are combined with a high level of complexity (i.e., where a fad requires behavioural changes so significant that causal and outcomes analysis are retarded), a fad becomes nonfalsifiable. That is to say, detractors cannot disprove claims about a fad's effectiveness. The nonfalsifiability of fads may be reinforced by the political, ideological and financial investment of adopters who have no desire to hear a critical analysis, even after the fad has passed.

But what influences managers to adopt or support management fads? Birnbaum posits six interrelated biases. These include role bias wherein academic managers feel pressured to take charge despite limited resources and understanding, ambiguous or conflicting goals, and intractable problems. Adopting fads offer managers an opportunity to appear to be in charge. Managers can also experience cognitive biases such as making decisions based on intuition rather than evidence, generalizing from favorable anecdotal evidence, and selectively assessing the impact of a technique on the organization. This may be reinforced via a placebo bias wherein the implementation of a fad masks symptoms without addressing the underlying problem. Normative bias can result in managers applying a logic of appropriateness (e.g., mimicking the actions of other managers in uncertain situations) over a logic of rational choice. Similarly, managers may adopt a fad to reinforce their self-image as effective at solving problems and influential in the organization (a self-efficacy bias). Finally, managers with their credibility heavily invested in a fad may have their judgment compromised by a commitment bias.

The positive and negative legacy of fads is difficult to assess. Birnbaum asserts that even limited exposure to fads may subtly alter the functioning of organizations as useful concepts, models and processes are incorporated into an institution. One positive effect of fads is pressure experienced by academic managers to recognize the importance of data in decision making. Fads also create opportunities for institutions to evolve by adopting new practices that better fit the environment, reinforce managers' commitment to engage and actively shape their environment, and trigger intra-institutional interaction. Finally, fads may draw institutional attention to specific issues such as cost effectiveness, innovations at other institutions and the like that, while important to external stakeholders (and therefore to maintaining institutional legitimacy), are not a high academic priority.

The negative effects of fads are legion. These include an overemphasis within and outside the academy on numbers that may reshape priorities towards the quantifiable or pressure institutions to alter their performance to get prettier numbers. For example, Alberta has adopted performance funding. A single PI (enrollment growth) has been responsible for the majority of the variance in funding awards. Expensive (but necessary) adult upgrading programs hamper institutions' ability to expand enrollment during this time of constrained funding and this pressures them to get out of upgrading and into other more cost-effective programming areas.

Persistent, public and possibly inappropriate inspection may in turn reduce trust in higher education. Similarly, justifying a fad by reference to a crisis in higher education reinforces the belief that higher education is in an almost constant state of crisis. Quantification may also give managers a false sense of certainty and undermine the value of decisions informed by intuition. The transient nature of fads can also give rise to cynicism within the community about managers and thereby reduce their influence. At the same time, the centralization required by many fads may undermine the autonomy of faculty—both individually and as a group.

Based upon Birnbaum's analysis, the most damaging outcome of fads appears to be their impact on the narrative that undergirds higher education. As Birnbaum writes,
In the United States, the educational narratives of the past have been stories of personal virtue, civic participation, democracy, and social justice. The narrative gods of the present appear to be economic utility, consumerism, and technology—a weak foundation on which to build a just social order or excite the imagination. The idea of higher education as a social institution has been displaced by higher education as an industry (p. 266).
Fads promote a narrative wherein business is portrayed as efficient and effective and higher education is not. Faculty members are often cast as the villains in this narrative as they resist the introduction of management techniques to protect their pay, privileges and status. When one accepts this characterization (as part of adopting a fad), the obvious solution is to subject higher education to the discipline of the market and reorder governance to mirror that of the private sector. Birnbaum argues:
[T]he simplicity of this narrative is its power, and the story of a small, privileged elite that benefits at the expense of the public is an evocative story that taps into the American psyche. So is the narrative of a fad that pledges to right the wrong and put the university in its place. Interesting stories are more likely than accurate ones to be accepted (p. 227).
As corporate priorities and practices creep into higher education, Management fads in higher education makes an important contribution to our understanding of how this will affect colleges, universities and technical institutes. Specifically, by codifying our knowledge of fads, this well written book gives us insight into the fad process as well as the impact of fads on institutions and, more broadly, upon the entire undertaking of higher education. Those who have (and those who have not) survived TQM, BPR, PIs, and their ilk will also find a reasoned explanation for their cynicism about new management fads. Perhaps more useful, Birnbaum's book may help faculty and administrators discover the positive outcomes that can flow from these elaborate exercises.

About the Reviewer

Bob Barnetson

Bob Barnetson is research and communications officer for the Alberta Colleges & Institutes Faculties Association. His areas of interest include higher education policy and academic labour.

References

Barnetson, B. & Cutright, M. (2000). Performance indicators as conceptual technologies. Higher education. 40 (3). 277-292

Birnbaum, R. (1988). How colleges work: The cybernetics of academic organizations and leadership. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.

Cohen, M.D., March, J.G. & Olsen, J.P. (1972). A garbage can model of organizational choice. Administrative science quarterly. 17 1-25.

Cutright, M. (ed.) (2001). Chaos theory and higher education: Leadership, planning, & policy. New York: Peter Lang Publishing.

Morgan, D. (1997). Images of organizations, 2nd Ed. London: SAGE.

[ home | overview | reviews | editors | submit | guidelines | announcements ]